KJEANRL, along with the University of Kentucky, will be observing the Thanksgiving Day holiday and no posts will be made the remainder of the week.
We are thankful for your support and wish you all a Happy Thanksgiving!
In this blog, 2L Staffer Madelyn Shelton discusses the interplay between the growing California wildfire crisis and the rising unavailability of homeowner’s insurance. She argues that the FAIR plan is only a partial solution, and more sustainable options are needed for the future.
In this blog, 2L Staffer Dylan Diedrich discusses the protections currently in place in Kentucky that are meant to protect pollinators such as bees and butterflies. Diedrich argues that the current protections, while admirable, are inadequate at protecting and restoring pollinator populations because they are voluntary. Since Kentucky primarily relies on voluntary educational programs to protect pollinators, there is no real deterrent to prevent individuals from harming pollinators. Diedrich proposes a system involving true sanctions to encourage proper administration of pesticides to protect pollinator populations.
Blog By: Ben Robinson
In this blog, 2L Staffer Ben Robinson discusses the environmental ideals explaining how other countries have come to give nature "natural rights". He further advocates for a possible solution that replicates the international concept of natural rights, while conforming to and working within the United States legal system.
Blog By: Phillip Burress
In the summer of 2024, the Supreme Court overturned a precedent relied upon for decades by federal agencies. In this blog, 3L Staffer Phillip Burress discusses that with the death of Chevron deference, federal agencies face new challenges and an increased risk of litigation for interpretations they make on ambiguous statutes. Burress points out that many agencies have been preparing for this change for the past decade, and the threat this change imposes may not be as severe as many people think.
In this blog, 3L Staffer Bailey Truitt discusses the current trend of selling horse farms and the push to divide the land into housing in Lexington and all across Kentucky. Truitt discusses that while housing is necessary for Lexington, dividing up agricultural land is detrimental to the historical equine industry as well as contributing to the urban sprawl problem found in Lexington. Truitt argues that maintaining horse farms and agricultural land in and around Lexington is the best choice for the economic development and protection of historical business, as well as the prevention of urban sprawl.
KJEANRL, along with the University of Kentucky, will be observing the Thanksgiving Day holiday and no posts will be made the remainder of the week.
We are thankful for your support and wish you all a Happy Thanksgiving!
The following post was written by staff member Tanner James.
For many, there is something inherently unsettling about the notion of horse-slaughter. Anti-slaughter organizations have established a relatively strong presence on the internet, soliciting public activism in an effort to eradicate all vestiges of the largely-illegal industry. See Stop Horse Slaughter Home Page, http://www.stophorseslaughter.com (last visited Nov. 16, 2009); Just Say Whoa!, http://www.justsaywhoa.org (last visited Nov. 16, 2009). In fact, this sentiment has reached all the way to Capitol Hill—especially through the efforts of Michigan Representative John Conyers, Jr.
On January 14, 2009, Rep. Conyers introduced H.R. 503, to be known as the Prevention of Equine Cruelty Act of 2009, a bill identical to his Prevention of Equine Cruelty Act of 2008. Prevention of Equine Cruelty Act, H.R. 503, 111th Cong. (2009); Prevention of Equine Cruelty Act, H.R. 6598, 110th Cong. (2008). This proposed bill would amend Chapter 3 of Title 18 of the U.S. Code, adding language that would criminalize the practice of knowingly "possess[ing], [shipping], transport[ing], purchas[ing], sell[ing], deliver[ing], or receiv[ing], in or affecting interstate commerce or foreign commerce, any horse [or horse carcass] with the intent that it is to be slaughtered [or used] for human consumption." Id. Engaging in this prohibited conduct could carry a three-year prison sentence. Id.
Surely, such a statute would require a relatively solid foundation—some well-established, persuasive reason—for potentially imprisoning a future violator. And yet, if such reasoning exists, it has not been well-represented by Mr. Conyers. In his House Report, submitted during the second session of the 110th Congress, the section entitled "Background and Need for the Legislation" seems to be little more than an emotional appeal to animal-lovers and owners. H.R. Rep. No. 110-901, at 2 (2008).
The report begins with a brief recap of relevant state case law and moves on to define the term "horse slaughter," followed by an acknowledgment that the practice of horse slaughter has not been eradicated, but merely modified into an industry of international transport. Id. at 2-5.Ultimately, when the time arrives for justifying the bill, Conyers relies upon three distinct-yet-similar reasons:
(1) Sellers who auction their horses may be devastated to learn that the buyer was in the business of slaughtering;
(2) The transportation is inhumane; and
(3) The methods of slaughter are inhumane.
See id.
Each of these "reasons" appears to be little more than an appeal to sympathy. As additional evidence of that point, one entire paragraph of the report is devoted to describing a particular slaughter method that is common in Mexico. Id.The reader is given a brief introduction to the method, followed by an illustration of a worst-case scenario wherein a horse was forced to endure "13 stabs in the [...] back before [it] collapsed." Id.Certainly, images such as this are not pleasant, but the question remains: Are these reasons sufficient to justify a federal statute? Furthermore, are these "inhumane" conditions notably worse than those afforded other animals? The report offers no enlightenment.
The slaughter of livestock is nothing new. The methods of slaughter, when exposed to the public, are always sources of disgust. And yet, for some unspoken reason(s), Rep. Conyers suggests that horses are distinguishable from other livestock—that horses should be treated with more respect. But, the House Report doesn't elaborate; it doesn't offer rationally satisfactory arguments. It simply draws a conclusion, tugs on the collective heartstrings of the constituency, and waits for the bill to be passed (which has yet to occur). Perhaps, if there was a bit more reasoned persuasion, the Prevention of Equine Cruelty Act could find its way in to the U.S. Code.
The following post was written by staff member Katie Shoultz.
On December 31, 2009, favorable tax deductions for individuals with qualified conservation easements will expire. Farm and Dairy, Land conservation tax break is set to expire Dec. 31, http://www.farmanddairy.com/news/land-conservation-tax-break-is-set-to-expire-dec-31/13279.html (last visited Nov. 16, 2009). A conservation easement is a restriction placed on a piece of property. The Nature Conservancy, Conservation Easements, http://www.nature.org/aboutus/howwework/conservationmethods/privatelands/conservationeasements/about/art14925.html (last visited Nov. 16, 2009). In executing an easement, a landowner either donates or sells certain rights attached to his or her property whereby a private or public organization then agrees to enforce the landowner's promise not to exercise the rights. Id. Such easements are generally seen as favorable in the farming industry because they serve as a protective measure for family farms. Farm and Dairy, Land conservation tax break is set to expire Dec. 31, http://www.farmanddairy.com/news/land-conservation-tax-break-is-set-to-expire-dec-31/13279.html (last visited Nov. 16, 2009). Advocates of easements also tout the added benefit of creating needed cash flow for many in the farming industry. Juan Espinosa, Rocky Ford, Colo., Farmers Receive Tax Advantages by Conservation Easement, The Pueblo Chieftain, June 22, 2002 available at http://www.encyclopedia.com/doc/1G1-120638712.html. This cash flow is particularly beneficial in depressed economic times and can help encourage sustainability. From a greater public perspective - these tax benefits provide incentives to a crucial sector in our society as "[a]gricultural producers not only provide the food we eat, but open space, wildlife habitat, and potentially carbon sequestration." Private Landowner Network, Conservation Tax Provisions making their way through Congress, http://www.privatelandownernetwork.org/plnlo/taxprovisions.asp?pp=true (last visited Nov. 16, 2009). In fact, one source indicates that from 2003-2007, over a half million acres have been placed in conservation easements. Id.
Currently, the legislation allows landowners to take deductions of up to fifty percent of their adjusted gross income (AGI). Farm and Dairy, Land conservation tax break is set to expire Dec. 31, http://www.farmanddairy.com/news/land-conservation-tax-break-is-set-to-expire-dec-31/13279.html (last visited Nov. 16, 2009). This percentage "allows grantors to realize the value of preserved property more quickly." Id. Qualified farmers who earn more than half of their income from farming operations are allowed to deduct up to one hundred percent of their AGI. Id. The expiring legislation also provides a longer time period for those claiming such deductions. Id. Those who have taken advantage of the more favorable legislation have up to 16 years "to carry forward the unused balance(s)." Id. Prior to the legislation, only six years was allowed. Id. For further information, the IRS released Notice 2007-50 to provide guidance for such deductions. I.R.S. Notice 07-50, 2007-25 I.R.B. (Jan. 4, 2007).
Two bills are currently set before Congress that would extend the aforementioned benefits permanently - HR 1831 (the Conservation Easement Incentive Act) and S 812 (the Rural Heritage Conservation Extension Act). It would obviously be quite advantageous for individuals, particularly farmers and ranchers, interested in placing an easement on their property if such proposals were adopted. Permanency would also lend "legal certainty for those involved in these long term projects." Private Landowner Network, Conservation Tax Provisions making their way through Congress, http://www.privatelandownernetwork.org/plnlo/taxprovisions.asp?pp=true (last visited Nov. 16, 2009).
Appearing in JNREL Vol. 20, No. 1, the following Note was written by former staff member LeeAnne Edmonds Applegate. Staff member Katie Huddleston wrote the following abstract.
Law and economics arose in the 1970's as a legal theory that promoted the application of economic principles to the law. Despite many evolutions over the past three decades, the theory has remained and has been applied to many legal fields, including environmental law. Its application in this field provides an interesting example of the theory at work and of the various criticisms made of the theory.
From the standpoint of law and economics, commercial transactions that produce environmental effects result in market failure. In such transactions, the environmental effects of consumer activities are not included in the price of such activities. Rather, these additional costs are borne by the larger society, people outside of the actual commercial transaction. In economic terms, this is a market failure. Therefore, government regulation has evolved in an effort to rectify this market failure by making the cost of such transactions to the consumer more closely approximate the larger cost of the activity to society.
The modern trend is to rectify market failure through the use of a "sin tax." A "sin tax" uses tax incentives to promote environmentally beneficial behavior, while imposing taxes for environmentally damaging behavior. The major problem with this approach is that to determine the appropriate amount for the "sin tax," the government must calculate the value of the environment and the societal cost of damage to it.
There are two main theories as to how to make these seemingly impossible valuations. Preservationists seek to set the tax according to an evaluation of the intrinsic value of the environment in its natural state. Conservationists, on the other hand, think the tax should be set according to the value of the environment as a resource. For example, when a tree is cut down, preservationists would value that tree in accordance with its function of air purification, soil retention, animal habitat, etc. Conservationists would set the value of the tree based on the value of the lumber that could be derived from it.
Aside from these two theories on valuation, there are two methods of economic valuation that can be used in setting the taxes. First is the Market Price Method. This method is useful when a market actually exists for the parts of the environment sought to be valued, such as products or resources derived there from. The current market price for the "commodity" is measured and studied for changes over time. This method is useful because it uses actual, easily identifiable and understandable data. However, it has limited applicability because of the limited markets for the environment and environmental goods. The market price may also bad indicator of the true, underlying value to society of such goods and activities, merely perpetuating the problem of market failure.
The other option is the Contingent Value Method. This method involves surveys in which people are interviewed about various hypothetical situations and asked to put a dollar value on an environmental service or commodity. This method has the benefit of being more flexible than the Mark Price Method. However, critics cite the time and effort that must be put into designing such surveys, the lack of actual observation of consumer behavior and the possibly inaccurate results that could result from it.
The following post was written by staff member Derek Leslie.
Who is permitted to bring an action to protect the environment or a natural resource when it is threatened? As a plaintiff, the answer to that question can mean getting your foot in the door, or alternatively, having it slammed in your face. The question's significance, then, can hardly be underestimated and certainly cannot be overlooked. In the area of environmental law, where groups like the Sierra Club pursue court action protecting the environment, standing has been a contentious issue.
While statutes can expand and limit what is required for standing with respect to a particular cause of action, the Supreme Court has recognized three elements required for so-called "classical" standing. Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife, 504 U.S. 555, 560 (1992). First, the plaintiff must have suffered an injury in fact; this injury must be concrete and particularized as well as actual and imminent. Secondly, the injury and conduct complained of must be casually connected. Finally, it must be likely that a favorable decision of the court would redress the injury. Id. at 560-561.
It is easy for plaintiffs, particularly national environmental groups, to run afoul of the simple requirements, particularly with respect to the need for injury in fact. For example, what injury did an environmental group called 4 Clean Lakes, whose membership consists entirely of citizens from Town A, suffer when Citizen B pollutes Town B's lake, a lake no member of 4 Clean Lakes has ever visited? Obviously, it is more natural that an avid swimmer in Town B's lake brings a suit rather than any member of 4 Clean Lakes. This example implicitly acknowledges that a group may bring an action, however, where one of its members would have had standing to bring the action herself, the interests it seeks to protect are germane to its purpose, and neither the claim asserted nor the relief requested require the individual members' participation in the lawsuit. Hunt v. Washington State Apple Advertising Com'n, 432 U.S. 333, 333 (1997). The bar for an individual's injury in fact is actually fairly low. Plaintiffs may adequately allege injury in fact if they use the area in question, and the aesthetic and recreational values of the area will be diminished by the challenged activity. Friends of the Earth, Inc. v. Laidlaw Environmental Services, 528 U.S. 167, 183 (2000).
Looking to the policy reasons behind standing, the requirements appear to further these goals. Generally speaking, standing is meant to ensure that courts do not entertain litigation based on tenuous legal interests with parties who may not pursue claims as diligently as someone who is injured directly. Thus, standing requirements help to manage the number of cases on a court's docket and also helps to ensure robust litigation between fully invested parties. Nevertheless, some have considered these standards in an environmental case too stringent. In response, several states have passed their own Environmental Protection Acts, which among other things have reduced the requirements of standing in state environmental cases. Potential plaintiffs, therefore, would do well to be aware of their particular jurisdiction's stance on the requirements of standing.
Former staff member Dawn Franklin wrote the following comment appearing in JNREL Vol. 20 No. 2. Staff member Sunni Harris wrote the following abstract.
In 1972, Congress passed the first Whistleblower Provision to protect employees that were discriminated against because they testified or filed suit under the Water Pollution Act. Since 1972, almost every state has enacted whistleblower statues to protect those bringing suits under environmental bills. However, as law surrounding this area matures, the question has become whether anyone other than employees and "authorized representatives of employees" have standing to bring a whistleblower claim against a company.
The court in Anderson v. Dep't of Labor, 422 F.3d 1155 (10th Cir. 2005), seems to answer this question in the negative. In this case, the mayor of Denver appointed the Plaintiff to serve as a political appointee on Metro Reclamation District's ("Metro") board in hopes that she would represent the aims of Metro's employee union ("OCAW"). Metro is a wastewater treatment plant. When the plaintiff discovered that Metro was planning to accept treatment wastewater from a Superfund site, she immediately spoke out against the plan to the public and press. As a result, Metro threatened the plaintiff with censorship and other sanctions. In response, the plaintiff filed a suit alleging that Metro's actions violated seven environmental whistleblower provisions.
The Anderson court held that the plaintiff's status as a political appointee precluded her from bringing a lawsuit against Metro pursuant to whistleblower statutes. The court's reasoning was two-fold. First, it determined that the plain language and congressional intent of the whistleblower statutes excluded her from the scope of their protection. Second, it determined that Anderson could not serve two masters. Specifically, Anderson could not be both an agent for the state of Colorado as a political appointee and an authorized representative of the OCAW board.
The Anderson court seems to underestimate the value of non-employee whistleblowers. Non-employees, including political appointees such as the plaintiff, should not fear retaliation from an employer upon reporting employer violations. Without the protection of the law to allow them to perform their jobs feely, a nonemployee's job becomes nearly impossible. Thus, in the future, courts should expand protection of whistleblower statutes to cover non-employees.
The following post was written by staff member Natasha Farmer.
On June 26, 2009 the House of Representatives passed the American Clean Energy and Security Act, H.R. 2454, also known as the Waxman-Markey Bill. Pew Center on Global Climate Change, http://www.pewclimate.org/acesa (last visited Nov. 3, 2009). If passed by the Senate, the bill would cut emissions by putting a cap on planet-warming greenhouse gases. Id. Emission cuts would start in 2012 and this comprehensive legislation would regulate 85 percent of the overall economy, however because of vulnerability to climate change agriculture would not be directly regulated. Kentucky Resource Council, http://www.kyrc.org/webnewspro/125347301215435.shtml (last visited Nov. 3, 2009).
Kentucky Resources Council Director, Tom Fitzgerald, believes the Act offers agriculture a role in helping reduce greenhouse gas loading into the atmosphere. Id. Director Fitzgerald relied on a report issued by the U.S. Global Change Research Program to explain that many crops show positive responses to elevated carbon dioxide and low levels of warming. Id. In addition, weeds, diseases, and insects benefit from warming, and increased heat and weather extremes are likely to reduce livestock production. Id. With the implementation of this law, agriculture would thrive because of the reduced amount of heat caused by greenhouse gases.
Agriculture has much to gain from this widespread policy. The bill makes agriculture part of the solution by offering incentives, greenhouse gas offsets, and opportunities to supply bio-energy. Pew Center Global Climate Change, http://www.pewclimate.org/federal/what-waxman-markey-does-for-agriculture (last visited Nov. 9, 2009). Title III of the Act will provide gas emission allowances for agriculture projects that reduce pollution to prevent the conversion of land that would increase greenhouse emissions. Id. The Act will also increase the demand for bio-based forms of energy and provide incentives to stimulate this industry. Id. The Act requires that 20% of electricity come from renewable power by 2020. Id. This could incentivize wind power on agriculture farms. Id.
Even though this Act has benefits for agriculture, there are also cost increases associated. The cost for transitioning away from fossil fuels will most likely cause fossil-based energy and products such as nitrogen fertilizer to rise. Id. However, the overall benefits of this legislation to the agriculture sector outweigh the increased costs. Therefore, implementation should be the path taken.
Appearing in JNREL Vol. 21. No.1, the following comment was written by former staff member Haley Prevatt. Staff member Andrew Leung wrote the following abstract.
In deciding Brazoria County v. Texas Commission on Environmental Quality, 128 S.W.3d 728 (Tex. App. 2004), the Texas Appellate Court upheld legislation implementing environmental speed limits and other environmental regulations propagated by the Texas Transportation Commission as not violative of the Texas Clean Air Act, the Texas Transportation Code, and the Texas Administrative Procedure Act. "Watch Your Speed... The EPA is Ticketing in Brazoria County v. Texas Commission on Environmental Quality" examines the court's analysis and explains possible nationwide consequences of this decision.
The Federal Clean Air Act allows the Environmental Protection Agency ("EPA") to set national standards for cleanliness of ambient air, more commonly known as National Ambient Air Quality Standards ("NAAQS"). The NAAQS set permissible levels of pollutants in ambient air but do not contain a mandated method for obtaining that level. Because of the wide array of technological means available to meet NAAQS standards, each individual state has complete discretion to adopt a combination of control devices in order to meet national standards for ambient air.
In Brazoria County, the EPA found levels of pollutants elevated beyond the permissible NAASQ amounts in eight Texas counties in the Houston-Galveston area. The EPA subsequently ordered Texas to create a feasible plan to reduce pollutants to acceptable levels. In response, the Texas Commission on Environmental Quality ("TCEQ") implemented regulations which had three primary effects: (1) reducing of speed limits on state highways to 55 mph; (2) setting forth a vehicle inspection and maintenance program; and (3) prohibiting use of commercial lawn-maintenance equipment at times other than afternoon hours.
Brazoria County, one of the eight counties affected by the TCEQ regulations, brought suit against the TCEQ alleging that it exceeded its authority in promulgating the aforementioned regulations. The Court found that the implementation of the environmental speed limits ("ESLs") was an authorized act because the legislature later acted to ratify the ESLs statutorily. With respect to the vehicle inspection and maintenance and lawn-maintenance regulation, the Court held that they were beyond the scope of the Texas legislation because the regulations were implemented to meet federal NAAQS limitations.
Because the Court's decision in Brazoria County is legally sound and based primarily on precedent, it is unremarkable in that manner. One facet of the case left unaddressed by the court is the possible policy implications of the case. Here, residents of Brazoria County and eight neighboring counties were merely inconvenienced by the environmental regulations promulgated by the TCEQ. The Court's decision leaves open the possibility of more invasive regulation in Texas and the other states of the Union, perhaps even to the extent that the takings clause of the United States Constitution might be implicated.